What is the difference between feudalism and capitalism




















This is state capitalism or chronny capitalism which is nearly completely opposed to laissez-faire capitalism. This article pretty much covers every economic system that is not a completely commanded economy and labels it capitalism. I would also like to thank you for this interesting comparison.

Also I think one of the main differences is that with feudalism you were stuck in the same class. While in Capitalism, your class could change from generation to generation. The American Dream is what is sold to us and until that dream becomes more of a fantasy then I think capitalism is here to stay. Thats theoretical…as capitalism advances, those who inherit capital are likely to maintain their status where those who do not inherit capital are also likely to maintain their status.

In fact, the odds of rags to riches now are not enough to justify considering capitalism in the light that capitalists want us to. End all inheritance and limit the amount of concentration of wealth, and then we can discuss the virtue of capitalism. Karl Marx, the renowned economist, extolled a system which has brough misery and depredation to many hundreds of millions. And yet the article claims capitlism creats a wealth divide?

Capitalism does create a wealth divide—due to its innate amorality; it openly chases profit green market arrows over human well-being. When surplus piles up Capitalism seeks new markets to sell their excess off to. Now the poor can consume sub-par product and stop bitching and the rich can become dynastically wealthy. America is an oligarchy as reported in a Princeton study, or it is pseudo-feudalism. How many people do you think suffer and die under a capitalist system? Capitalism is the main source of inequality today.

Name required. Although it encourages people to compete against each other for a better position, it cannot provide enough space for everyone to reach the top o the pyramid, irrespective of the turmoil put into it. It mainly consisted of the classes, the royalty, the nobility, the knights, and the peasants.

The nobility held lands under the crown and leased it to the knights in exchange for military service and the peasants were obliged to live on the lands of the nobles and do them service. Unlike feudalism, every member of the society was involved with feudalism. It kept peace and protection among the land as well as maintained the stability of the kingdom, although the royalty and the nobility liked and supported it while the serfs and slaves did not enjoy it.

The king was the one who had complete control over the feudal system, owned all the land, and made decisions related to it. The barons, also called the nobles were powerful and wealthy people who chartered the land from the king and rented it out to the knights in exchange for the military service as demanded by the king. The lowest section of the society comprised of the vassals, serfs, slaves, or the peasantry.

These were the people who were under the protection of the barons and vowed them homage, fidelity, labor, and a part of their produce.

With the passage of time, there was advancement in means of communication that broke the stronghold of the monarchs as people disapproved the power being concentrated in the hands of kings.

The system of controlling and managing the resources got changed with other changes in the society and the world saw emergence of the social system of capitalism.

The birth of capitalism can be seen in a political and social system where the means of production does not remain in the hands of a noble or a monarch. A few people who invest in machinery and set up factories to hire the services of a working class are called capitalists and the system is referred to as capitalism. Capitalism is defined by individual rights and in political terms, it is referred to as laissez-faire that means freedom. There is a rule of law and it is a market driven economy.

Means of production and distribution remain in the hands of private individuals rather than remaining in the hands of the state. Land in England had for a long time been unusually concentrated, with big landlords holding an unusually large proportion, in conditions that enabled them to use their property in new ways.

What they lacked in 'extra-economic' powers of surplus extraction they more than made up for with increasing 'economic' powers.

This distinctive combination had significant consequences. On the one hand, the concentration of English landholding meant that an unusually large proportion of land was worked not by peasant-proprietors but by tenants the word 'farmer', incidentally, literally means 'tenant' - a usage suggested by phrases familiar today, such as 'farming out'.

This was true even before the waves of dispossession, especially in the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries, conventionally associated with 'enclosure', and was in contrast, for example, to France, where a larger proportion of land remained, and would long continue to remain, in the hands of peasants. On the other hand, the relatively weak extra-economic powers of landlords meant that they depended less on their ability to squeeze more rents out of their tenants by direct, coercive means than on their tenants' success in competitive production.

Agrarian landlords in this arrangement had a strong incentive to encourage - and, wherever possible, to compel - their tenants to find ways of reducing costs by increasing labour-productivity. In this respect, they were fundamentally different from rentier aristocrats, who throughout history have depended for their wealth on squeezing surpluses out of peasants by means of simple coercion, enhancing their powers of surplus extraction not by increasing the productivity of the direct producers but rather by improving their own coercive powers - military, judicial, and political.

As for the tenants, they were increasingly subject not only to direct pressures from landlords but also to market imperatives that compelled them to enhance their productivity. English tenancies took various forms, and there were many regional variations, but a growing number were subject to economic rents - rents fixed not by some legal or customary standard but by market conditions. There was, in effect, a market in leases.

Tenants were obliged to compete not only in a market for consumers but also in a market for access to land. The effect of this system of property relations was that many agricultural producers including prosperous 'yeomen' became market-dependent in their access to land itself, to the means of production. Increasingly, as more land came under this economic regime, advantage in access to the land itself would go to those who could produce competitively and pay good rents by increasing their own productivity.

This meant that success would breed success, and competitive farmers would have increasing access to even more land, while others lost access altogether. This market-mediated relation between landlords and peasants is visible in the attitude to rents that was emerging by the sixteenth century. In a system of 'competitive rents', in which landlords, wherever possible, would effectively lease land to the highest bidder, at whatever rent the market would bear, they - and their surveyors became increasingly conscious of the difference between the fIxed rents paid by customary tenants and an economic rent determined by the market.

We can watch the development of a new mentality by observing the landlord's surveyor as he computes the rental value of land on the basis of some more or less abstract principle of market value, and measures it explicitly against the actual rents being paid by customary tenants. Here, in the careful estimates of these surveyors, who talk about 'the annual value beyond rent' or 'value above the oulde [sic] rent', and in their calculation of what they consider to be the unearned increment that goes to the copyhold tenant paying a customary rent below the value of land determined by competitive market conditions, we have the rudiments of later, more sophisticated theories of value and capitalist ground rent.

These conceptions of value are based on the very concrete experience of landlords at a critical moment in the development of the competitive system of agrarian capitalism. The development of these economic rents illustrates the difference between the market as opportunity and the market as imperative. It also exposes the deficiencies in accounts of capitalist development based on the conventional assumptions.

The ways in which those assumptions have determined perceptions of the evidence is nicely illustrated in an important article from the transition debate on the structural role of towns in feudalism. John Merrington suggests that although the transformation of feudal surplus labour into monetary rents did not in itself alter the fundamental nature of feudal relations, it did have one important consequence: by helping to ftx surplus labour to a constant magnitude it 'stimulated the growth of independent commodity production.

But this proposition seems to be based less on empirical evidence than on the market-as-opportunity model, with its assumption that petty producers would choose to act like capitalists if only given the chance. The effects of monetary rents varied widely according to the property relations between the peasants who produced those rents and the landlords who appropriated them.

Where the extra-economic powers of feudal lords remained strong, peasants could be subjected to the same coercive pressures as before from landlords seeking to squeeze more surplus labour out of them, even if now it took the form of monetary rents instead of labour services.

Where, as in France, the peasants' hold on property was strong enough to resist such increasing pressures from landlords, rents were often fixed at a nominal rate. Surely it is precisely in a case like this, with peasants enjoying secure property rights and subject not only to fixed but also to modest rents, that we might, on the basis of Merrington's assumptions, expect to find a stimulus to commodity production that might eventually give rise to capitalism.

But the effect was just the opposite. The evidence outlined by Brenner suggests that it was not fixed rents of this kind that stimulated the growth of commodity production. On the contrary, it was unfixed, variable rents responsive to market imperatives that in England stimulated the development of commodity production, the improvement of productivity, and self-sustaining economic development.

In France, precisely because peasants typically enjoyed possession of land at fixed and nominal rents, no such stimulus existed. It was, in other words, not the opportunities afforded by the market but rather its imperatives that drove petty commodity producers to accumulate. By the early modern period, even many customary leases in England had effectively become economic leases of this kind.

But even those tenants who enjoyed some kind of customary tenure that gave them more security, but who might still be obliged to sell their produce in the same markets, could go under in conditions where competitive standards of productivity were being set by farmers responding more directly and urgently to the pressures of the market.

The same would increasingly be true even of landowners working their own land.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000